Lockes Eigentumsbegriff (IH): Unterschied zwischen den Versionen

Aus Philo Wiki
Wechseln zu:Navigation, Suche
(add text)
K (cut)
 
(Eine dazwischenliegende Version desselben Benutzers wird nicht angezeigt)
Zeile 1: Zeile 1:
CHAP.  V. Of PROPERTY.
+
CHAP.  V. OF PROPERTY.
  
 
Sec. 25.  Whether we consider natural reason, which tells  
 
Sec. 25.  Whether we consider natural reason, which tells  
Zeile 17: Zeile 17:
 
supposition, that God gave the world to Adam, and his heirs in  
 
supposition, that God gave the world to Adam, and his heirs in  
 
succession, exclusive of all the rest of his posterity.  But I  
 
succession, exclusive of all the rest of his posterity.  But I  
shall endeavour to shew, how men might come to have a property  
+
shall <font color="purple">endeavour to shew, how men might come to have a property  
in several parts of that which God gave to mankind in common, and  
+
in several parts of that which God gave to mankind in common</font>, and  
 
that without any express compact of all the commoners.
 
that without any express compact of all the commoners.
  
Zeile 27: Zeile 27:
 
being.  And tho' all the fruits it naturally produces, and beasts  
 
being.  And tho' all the fruits it naturally produces, and beasts  
 
it feeds, belong to mankind in common, as they are produced by  
 
it feeds, belong to mankind in common, as they are produced by  
the spontaneous hand of nature; and no body has originally a  
+
the spontaneous hand of nature; and <font color="purple">no body has originally a  
 
private dominion, exclusive of the rest of mankind, in any of  
 
private dominion, exclusive of the rest of mankind, in any of  
them, as they are thus in their natural state: yet being given  
+
them, as they are thus in their natural state</font>: yet being given  
 
for the use of men, there must of necessity be a means to  
 
for the use of men, there must of necessity be a means to  
 
appropriate them some way or other, before they can be of any  
 
appropriate them some way or other, before they can be of any  
Zeile 40: Zeile 40:
  
 
Sec. 27.  Though the earth, and all inferior creatures, be  
 
Sec. 27.  Though the earth, and all inferior creatures, be  
common to all men, yet every man has a property in his own  
+
common to all men, yet <font color="purple">every man has a property in his own  
person: this no body has any right to but himself.  The  
+
person: this no body has any right to but himself</font>.  The  
 
labour of his body, and the work of his hands, we may say,  
 
labour of his body, and the work of his hands, we may say,  
are properly his.  Whatsoever then he removes out of the state  
+
<font color="purple">are properly his</font>.  Whatsoever then he removes out of the state  
that nature hath provided, and left it in, he hath mixed his  
+
that nature hath provided, and left it in, <font color="purple">he hath mixed his  
labour with, and joined to it something that is his own, and  
+
labour with, and joined to it something that is his own</font>, and  
 
thereby makes it his property.  It being by him removed from  
 
thereby makes it his property.  It being by him removed from  
 
the common state nature hath placed it in, it hath by this  
 
the common state nature hath placed it in, it hath by this  
Zeile 51: Zeile 51:
 
of other men: for this labour being the unquestionable property  
 
of other men: for this labour being the unquestionable property  
 
of the labourer, no man but he can have a right to what that is  
 
of the labourer, no man but he can have a right to what that is  
once joined to, at least where there is enough, and as good, left  
+
once joined to, <font color="purple">at least where there is enough, and as good, left  
in common for others.
+
in common for others</font>.
  
 
Sec. 28.  He that is nourished by the acorns he picked up  
 
Sec. 28.  He that is nourished by the acorns he picked up  
Zeile 61: Zeile 61:
 
or when he brought them home? or when he picked them up? and it  
 
or when he brought them home? or when he picked them up? and it  
 
is plain, if the first gathering made them not his, nothing else  
 
is plain, if the first gathering made them not his, nothing else  
could.  That labour put a distinction between them and common:  
+
could.  <font color="purple">That labour put a distinction between them and common:  
 
that added something to them more than nature, the common mother  
 
that added something to them more than nature, the common mother  
of all, had done; and so they became his private right.  And will  
+
of all, had done; and so they became his private right</font>.  And will  
 
any one say, he had no right to those acorns or apples, he thus  
 
any one say, he had no right to those acorns or apples, he thus  
 
appropriated, because he had not the consent of all mankind to  
 
appropriated, because he had not the consent of all mankind to  
Zeile 69: Zeile 69:
 
belonged to all in common?  If such a consent as that was  
 
belonged to all in common?  If such a consent as that was  
 
necessary, man had starved, notwithstanding the plenty God had  
 
necessary, man had starved, notwithstanding the plenty God had  
given him.  We see in commons, which remain so by compact, that  
+
given him.  <font color="purple">We see in commons, which remain so by compact, that  
 
it is the taking any part of what is common, and removing it out  
 
it is the taking any part of what is common, and removing it out  
 
of the state nature leaves it in, which begins the property;  
 
of the state nature leaves it in, which begins the property;  
 
without which the common is of no use.  And the taking of this or  
 
without which the common is of no use.  And the taking of this or  
 
that part, does not depend on the express consent of all the  
 
that part, does not depend on the express consent of all the  
commoners.  Thus the grass my horse has bit; the turfs my servant  
+
commoners</font>.  Thus the grass my horse has bit; the turfs my servant  
 
has cut; and the ore I have digged in any place, where I have a  
 
has cut; and the ore I have digged in any place, where I have a  
 
right to them in common with others, become my property,  
 
right to them in common with others, become my property,  
Zeile 92: Zeile 92:
 
thereby appropriated it to himself.
 
thereby appropriated it to himself.
  
Sec. 30. Thus this law of reason makes the deer that
+
...
Indian's who hath killed it; it is allowed to be his goods, who
 
hath bestowed his labour upon it, though before it was the common
 
right of every one.  And amongst those who are counted the
 
civilized part of mankind, who have made and multiplied positive
 
laws to determine property, this original law of nature, for
 
the beginning of property, in what was before common, still
 
takes place; and by virtue thereof, what fish any one catches in
 
the ocean, that great and still remaining common of mankind; or
 
what ambergrise any one takes up here, is by the labour that
 
removes it out of that common state nature left it in, made his
 
property, who takes that pains about it.  And even amongst us,
 
the hare that any one is hunting, is thought his who pursues her
 
during the chase: for being a beast that is still looked upon as
 
common, and no man's private possession; whoever has employed so
 
much labour about any of that kind, as to find and pursue her,
 
has thereby removed her from the state of nature, wherein she was
 
common, and hath begun a property.
 
  
 
Sec. 31.  It will perhaps be objected to this, that if  
 
Sec. 31.  It will perhaps be objected to this, that if  
Zeile 118: Zeile 101:
 
too.  God has given us all things richly, 1 Tim.  vi.  12.  is  
 
too.  God has given us all things richly, 1 Tim.  vi.  12.  is  
 
the voice of reason confirmed by inspiration.  But how far has he  
 
the voice of reason confirmed by inspiration.  But how far has he  
given it us?  To enjoy.  As much as any one can make use of to  
+
given it us?  To enjoy.  <font color="purple">As much as any one can make use of to  
 
any advantage of life before it spoils, so much he may by his  
 
any advantage of life before it spoils, so much he may by his  
Tabour fix a property in: whatever is beyond this, is more than  
+
labour fix a property in: whatever is beyond this, is more than  
his share, and belongs to others.  Nothing was made by God for  
+
his share, and belongs to others</font>.  Nothing was made by God for  
 
man to spoil or destroy.  And thus, considering the plenty of  
 
man to spoil or destroy.  And thus, considering the plenty of  
 
natural provisions there was a long time in the world, and the  
 
natural provisions there was a long time in the world, and the  
Zeile 166: Zeile 149:
 
gave it them for their benefit, and the greatest conveniencies of  
 
gave it them for their benefit, and the greatest conveniencies of  
 
life they were capable to draw from it, it cannot be supposed he  
 
life they were capable to draw from it, it cannot be supposed he  
meant it should always remain common and uncultivated.  He gave  
+
meant it should always remain common and uncultivated.  <font color="purple">He gave  
 
it to the use of the industrious and rational, (and labour was  
 
it to the use of the industrious and rational, (and labour was  
 
to be his title to it;) not to the fancy or covetousness of the  
 
to be his title to it;) not to the fancy or covetousness of the  
quarrelsome and contentious.  He that had as good left for his  
+
quarrelsome and contentious.</font> He that had as good left for his  
 
improvement, as was already taken up, needed not complain, ought  
 
improvement, as was already taken up, needed not complain, ought  
 
not to meddle with what was already improved by another's labour:  
 
not to meddle with what was already improved by another's labour:  
Zeile 178: Zeile 161:
 
to do with, or his industry could reach to.
 
to do with, or his industry could reach to.
  
Sec. 35. It is true, in land that is common in
+
...
England, or any other country, where there is plenty of people
 
under government, who have money and commerce, no one can inclose
 
or appropriate any part, without the consent of all his fellow-
 
commoners; because this is left common by compact, i.e. by the
 
law of the land, which is not to be violated.  And though it be
 
common, in respect of some men, it is not so to all mankind; but
 
is the joint property of this country, or this parish.  Besides,
 
the remainder, after such enclosure, would not be as good to the
 
rest of the commoners, as the whole was when they could all make
 
use of the whole; whereas in the beginning and first peopling of
 
the great common of the world, it was quite otherwise.  The law
 
man was under, was rather for appropriating.  God commanded, and
 
his wants forced him to labour.  That was his property which
 
could not be taken from him where-ever he had fixed it.  And
 
hence subduing or cultivating the earth, and having dominion, we
 
see are joined together.  The one gave title to the other.  So
 
that God, by commanding to subdue, gave authority so far to
 
appropriate: and the condition of human life, which requires
 
labour and materials to work on, necessarily introduces private
 
possessions.
 
  
 
Sec. 36.  The measure of property nature has well set by  
 
Sec. 36.  The measure of property nature has well set by  
Zeile 208: Zeile 171:
 
his neighbour, who would still have room for as good, and as  
 
his neighbour, who would still have room for as good, and as  
 
large a possession (after the other had taken out his) as before  
 
large a possession (after the other had taken out his) as before  
it was appropriated.  This measure did confine every man's  
+
it was appropriated.  <font color="purple">This measure did confine every man's  
 
possession to a very moderate proportion, and such as he might  
 
possession to a very moderate proportion, and such as he might  
appropriate to himself, without injury to any body, in the first  
+
appropriate to himself, without injury to any body</font>, in the first  
 
ages of the world, when men were more in danger to be lost, by  
 
ages of the world, when men were more in danger to be lost, by  
 
wandering from their company, in the then vast wilderness of the  
 
wandering from their company, in the then vast wilderness of the  
Zeile 224: Zeile 187:
 
injured by this man's incroachment, though the race of men have  
 
injured by this man's incroachment, though the race of men have  
 
now spread themselves to all the corners of the world, and do  
 
now spread themselves to all the corners of the world, and do  
 
 
infinitely exceed the small number was at the beginning.  Nay,  
 
infinitely exceed the small number was at the beginning.  Nay,  
 
the extent of ground is of so little value, without labour,  
 
the extent of ground is of so little value, without labour,  
Zeile 253: Zeile 215:
 
not be much, nor to the prejudice of others, where the same  
 
not be much, nor to the prejudice of others, where the same  
 
plenty was still left to those who would use the same industry.   
 
plenty was still left to those who would use the same industry.   
To which let me add, that he who appropriates land to himself by
 
his labour, does not lessen, but increase the common stock of
 
mankind: for the provisions serving to the support of human life,
 
produced by one acre of inclosed and cultivated land, are (to
 
speak much within compass) ten times more than those which are
 
yielded by an acre of land of an equal richness lying waste in
 
common.  And therefore he that incloses land, and has a greater
 
plenty of the conveniencies of life from ten acres, than he could
 
have from an hundred left to nature, may truly be said to give
 
ninety acres to mankind: for his labour now supplies him with
 
provisions out of ten acres, which were but the product of an
 
hundred lying in common.  I have here rated the improved land
 
very low, in making its product but as ten to one, when it is
 
much nearer an hundred to one: for I ask, whether in the wild
 
woods and uncultivated waste of America, left to nature,
 
without any improvement, tillage or husbandry, a thousand acres
 
yield the needy and wretched inhabitants as many conveniencies of
 
life, as ten acres of equally fertile land do in Devonshire,
 
where they are well cultivated?
 
 
Before the appropriation of land, he who gathered as much of
 
the wild fruit, killed, caught, or tamed, as many of the beasts,
 
as he could; he that so imployed his pains about any of the
 
spontaneous products of nature, as any way to alter them from the
 
state which nature put them in, by placing any of his labour
 
on them, did thereby acquire a propriety in them: but if they
 
perished, in his possession, without their due use; if the fruits
 
rotted, or the venison putrified, before he could spend it, he
 
offended against the common law of nature, and was liable to be
 
punished; he invaded his neighbour's share, for he had no right,
 
farther than his use called for any of them, and they might
 
serve to afford him conveniencies of life.
 
 
Sec. 38.  The same measures governed the possession of
 
land too: whatsoever he tilled and reaped, laid up and made use
 
of, before it spoiled, that was his peculiar right; whatsoever he
 
enclosed, and could feed, and make use of, the cattle and product
 
was also his.  But if either the grass of his enclosure rotted on
 
the ground, or the fruit of his planting perished without
 
gathering, and laying up, this part of the earth, notwithstanding
 
his enclosure, was still to be looked on as waste, and might be
 
 
the possession of any other.  Thus, at the beginning, Cain
 
might take as much ground as he could till, and make it his own
 
land, and yet leave enough to Abel's sheep to feed on; a few
 
acres would serve for both their possessions.  But as families
 
increased, and industry inlarged their stocks, their possessions
 
inlarged with the need of them; but yet it was commonly without
 
any fixed property in the ground they made use of, till they
 
incorporated, settled themselves together, and built cities; and
 
then, by consent, they came in time, to set out the bounds of
 
their distinct territories, and agree on limits between them and
 
their neighbours; and by laws within themselves, settled the
 
properties of those of the same society: for we see, that in
 
that part of the world which was first inhabited, and therefore
 
like to be best peopled, even as low down as Abraham's time,
 
they wandered with their flocks, and their herds, which was their
 
substance, freely up and down; and this Abraham did, in a
 
country where he was a stranger.  Whence it is plain, that at
 
least a great part of the land lay in common; that the
 
inhabitants valued it not, nor claimed property in any more than
 
they made use of.  But when there was not room enough in the same
 
place, for their herds to feed together, they by consent, as
 
Abraham and Lot did, Gen. xiii.  5.  separated and inlarged
 
their pasture, where it best liked them.  And for the same reason
 
Esau went from his father, and his brother, and planted in
 
mount Seir, Gen. xxxvi. 6.
 
 
Sec. 39.  And thus, without supposing any private dominion,
 
and property in Adam, over all the world, exclusive of all
 
other men, which can no way be proved, nor any one's property be
 
made out from it; but supposing the world given, as it was, to
 
the children of men in common, we see how labour could make
 
men distinct titles to several parcels of it, for their private
 
uses; wherein there could be no doubt of right, no room for
 
quarrel.
 
 
Sec. 40.  Nor is it so strange, as perhaps before
 
consideration it may appear, that the property of labour should
 
be able to over-balance the community of land: for it is labour
 
indeed that puts the difference of value on every thing; and
 
let any one consider what the difference is between an acre of
 
land planted with tobacco or sugar, sown with wheat or barley,
 
and an acre of the same land lying in common, without any
 
husbandry upon it, and he will find, that the improvement of
 
labour makes the far greater part of the value.  I think it
 
will be but a very modest computation to say, that of the
 
products of the earth useful to the life of man nine tenths are
 
the effects of labour: nay, if we will rightly estimate things
 
as they come to our use, and cast up the several expences about
 
them, what in them is purely owing to nature, and what to
 
labour, we shall find, that in most of them ninety-nine
 
hundredths are wholly to be put on the account of labour. 
 
 
Sec. 41.  There cannot be a clearer demonstration of any
 
thing, than several nations of the Americans are of this, who
 
are rich in land, and poor in all the comforts of life; whom
 
nature having furnished as liberally as any other people, with
 
the materials of plenty, i.e. a fruitful soil, apt to produce
 
in abundance, what might serve for food, raiment, and delight;
 
yet for want of improving it by labour, have not one hundredth
 
part of the conveniencies we enjoy: and a king of a large and
 
fruitful territory there, feeds, lodges, and is clad worse than a
 
day-labourer in England. 
 
  
Sec. 42. To make this a little clearer, let us but trace
+
...
some of the ordinary provisions of life, through their several
 
progresses, before they come to our use, and see how much they
 
receive of their value from human industry.  Bread, wine and
 
cloth, are things of daily use, and great plenty; yet
 
notwithstanding, acorns, water and leaves, or skins, must be our
 
bread, drink and cloathing, did not labour furnish us with
 
 
 
these more useful commodities: for whatever bread is more worth
 
than acorns, wine than water, and cloth or silk, than leaves,
 
skins or moss, that is wholly owing to labour and industry;
 
the one of these being the food and raiment which unassisted
 
nature furnishes us with; the other, provisions which our
 
industry and pains prepare for us, which how much they exceed the
 
other in value, when any one hath computed, he will then see how
 
much labour makes the far greatest part of the value of things
 
we enjoy in this world: and the ground which produces the
 
materials, is scarce to be reckoned in, as any, or at most, but a
 
very small part of it; so little, that even amongst us, land that
 
is left wholly to nature, that hath no improvement of pasturage,
 
tillage, or planting, is called, as indeed it is, waste; and we
 
shall find the benefit of it amount to little more than nothing.
 
 
 
This shews how much numbers of men are to be preferred to
 
largeness of dominions; and that the increase of lands, and the
 
right employing of them, is the great art of government: and that
 
prince, who shall be so wise and godlike, as by established laws
 
of liberty to secure protection and encouragement to the honest
 
industry of mankind, against the oppression of power and
 
narrowness of party, will quickly be too hard for his neighbours:
 
but this by the by.  To return to the argument in hand,
 
 
 
Sec. 43.  An acre of land, that bears here twenty bushels of
 
wheat, and another in America, which, with the same husbandry,
 
would do the like, are, without doubt, of the same natural
 
intrinsic value: but yet the benefit mankind receives from the
 
one in a year, is worth 5l.  and from the other possibly not
 
worth a penny, if all the profit an Indian received from it were
 
to be valued, and sold here; at least, I may truly say, not one
 
thousandth.  It is labour then which puts the greatest part of
 
value upon land, without which it would scarcely be worth any
 
thing: it is to that we owe the greatest part of all its useful
 
products; for all that the straw, bran, bread, of that acre of
 
wheat, is more worth than the product of an acre of as good land,
 
which lies waste, is all the effect of labour: for it is not
 
barely the plough-man's pains, the reaper's and thresher's toil,
 
and the baker's sweat, is to be counted into the bread we eat;
 
the labour of those who broke the oxen, who digged and wrought
 
the iron and stones, who felled and framed the timber employed
 
about the plough, mill, oven, or any other utensils, which are a
 
vast number, requisite to this corn, from its being feed to be
 
sown to its being made bread, must all be charged on the
 
account of labour, and received as an effect of that: nature and
 
the earth furnished only the almost worthless materials, as in
 
themselves.  It would be a strange catalogue of things, that
 
industry provided and made use of, about every loaf of bread,
 
before it came to our use, if we could trace them; iron, wood,
 
leather, bark, timber, stone, bricks, coals, lime, cloth, dying
 
drugs, pitch, tar, masts, ropes, and all the materials made use
 
of in the ship, that brought any of the commodities made use of
 
by any of the workmen, to any part of the work; all which it
 
would be almost impossible, at least too long, to reckon up.
 
 
 
Sec. 44.  From all which it is evident, that though the
 
things of nature are given in common, yet man, by being master of
 
himself, and proprietor of his own person, and the actions or
 
labour of it, had still in himself the great foundation of
 
property; and that, which made up the great part of what he
 
applied to the support or comfort of his being, when invention
 
and arts had improved the conveniencies of life, was perfectly
 
his own, and did not belong in common to others.
 
 
 
Sec. 45.  Thus labour, in the beginning, gave a right of
 
property, wherever any one was pleased to employ it upon what
 
was common, which remained a long while the far greater part, and
 
is yet more than mankind makes use of.  Men, at first, for the
 
most part, contented themselves with what unassisted nature
 
offered to their necessities: and though afterwards, in some
 
 
 
parts of the world, (where the increase of people and stock, with
 
the use of money, had made land scarce, and so of some value)
 
the several communities settled the bounds of their distinct
 
territories, and by laws within themselves regulated the
 
properties of the private men of their society, and so, by
 
compact and agreement, settled the property which labour and
 
industry began; and the leagues that have been made between
 
several states and kingdoms, either expresly or tacitly disowning
 
all claim and right to the land in the others possession, have,
 
by common consent, given up their pretences to their natural
 
common right, which originally they had to those countries, and
 
so have, by positive agreement, settled a property amongst
 
themselves, in distinct parts and parcels of the earth; yet there
 
are still great tracts of ground to be found, which (the
 
inhabitants thereof not having joined with the rest of mankind,
 
in the consent of the use of their common money) lie waste, and
 
are more than the people who dwell on it do, or can make use of,
 
and so still lie in common; tho' this can scarce happen amongst
 
that part of mankind that have consented to the use of money.
 
  
 
Sec. 46.  The greatest part of things really useful to the  
 
Sec. 46.  The greatest part of things really useful to the  
Zeile 464: Zeile 225:
 
themselves: gold, silver and diamonds, are things that fancy or  
 
themselves: gold, silver and diamonds, are things that fancy or  
 
agreement hath put the value on, more than real use, and the  
 
agreement hath put the value on, more than real use, and the  
necessary support of life. Now of those good things which nature
+
necessary support of life.
hath provided in common, every one had a right (as hath been
+
 
said) to as much as he could use, and property in all that he
+
...
could effect with his labour; all that his industry could
 
extend to, to alter from the state nature had put it in, was his.
 
He that gathered a hundred bushels of acorns or apples, had
 
thereby a property in them, they were his goods as soon as
 
gathered. He was only to look, that he used them before they
 
spoiled, else he took more than his share, and robbed others. 
 
And indeed it was a foolish thing, as well as dishonest, to hoard
 
up more than he could make use of.  If he gave away a part to any
 
body else, so that it perished not uselesly in his possession,
 
these he also made use of.  And if he also bartered away plums,
 
that would have rotted in a week, for nuts that would last good
 
for his eating a whole year, he did no injury; he wasted not the
 
common stock; destroyed no part of the portion of goods that
 
belonged to others, so long as nothing perished uselesly in his
 
hands.  Again, if he would give his nuts for a piece of metal,
 
pleased with its colour; or exchange his sheep for shells, or
 
wool for a sparkling pebble or a diamond, and keep those by him
 
all his life he invaded not the right of others, he might heap up
 
as much of these durable things as he pleased; the exceeding of
 
the bounds of his just property not lying in the largeness of
 
his possession, but the perishing of any thing uselesly in it.
 
  
 
Sec. 47.  And thus came in the use of money, some lasting  
 
Sec. 47.  And thus came in the use of money, some lasting  
Zeile 493: Zeile 233:
 
consent men would take in exchange for the truly useful, but  
 
consent men would take in exchange for the truly useful, but  
 
perishable supports of life.
 
perishable supports of life.
 +
 +
...
  
 
Sec. 48.  And as different degrees of industry were apt to  
 
Sec. 48.  And as different degrees of industry were apt to  
Zeile 503: Zeile 245:
 
hundred thousand times as many, but nothing in the island, either  
 
hundred thousand times as many, but nothing in the island, either  
 
because of its commonness, or perishableness, fit to supply the  
 
because of its commonness, or perishableness, fit to supply the  
place of money; what reason could any one have there to enlarge  
+
place of money; <font color="purple">what reason could any one have there to enlarge  
 
his possessions beyond the use of his family, and a plentiful  
 
his possessions beyond the use of his family, and a plentiful  
 
supply to its consumption, either in what their own industry  
 
supply to its consumption, either in what their own industry  
 
produced, or they could barter for like perishable, useful  
 
produced, or they could barter for like perishable, useful  
commodities, with others?  Where there is not some thing, both  
+
commodities, with others?</font> Where there is not some thing, both  
 
lasting and scarce, and so valuable to be hoarded up, there men  
 
lasting and scarce, and so valuable to be hoarded up, there men  
 
will not be apt to enlarge their possessions of land, were it  
 
will not be apt to enlarge their possessions of land, were it  

Aktuelle Version vom 14. Mai 2010, 06:30 Uhr

CHAP. V. OF PROPERTY.

Sec. 25. Whether we consider natural reason, which tells us, that men, being once born, have a right to their preservation, and consequently to meat and drink, and such other things as nature affords for their subsistence: or revelation, which gives us an account of those grants God made of the world to Adam, and to Noah, and his sons, it is very clear, that God, as king David says, Psal. cxv. 16. has given the earth to the children of men; given it to mankind in common. But this being supposed, it seems to some a very great difficulty, how any one should ever come to have a property in any thing: I will not content myself to answer, that if it be difficult to make out property, upon a supposition that God gave the world to Adam, and his posterity in common, it is impossible that any man, but one universal monarch, should have any property upon a supposition, that God gave the world to Adam, and his heirs in succession, exclusive of all the rest of his posterity. But I shall endeavour to shew, how men might come to have a property in several parts of that which God gave to mankind in common, and that without any express compact of all the commoners.

Sec. 26. God, who hath given the world to men in common, hath also given them reason to make use of it to the best advantage of life, and convenience. The earth, and all that is therein, is given to men for the support and comfort of their being. And tho' all the fruits it naturally produces, and beasts it feeds, belong to mankind in common, as they are produced by the spontaneous hand of nature; and no body has originally a private dominion, exclusive of the rest of mankind, in any of them, as they are thus in their natural state: yet being given for the use of men, there must of necessity be a means to appropriate them some way or other, before they can be of any use, or at all beneficial to any particular man. The fruit, or venison, which nourishes the wild Indian, who knows no enclosure, and is still a tenant in common, must be his, and so his, i.e. a part of him, that another can no longer have any right to it, before it can do him any good for the support of his life.

Sec. 27. Though the earth, and all inferior creatures, be common to all men, yet every man has a property in his own person: this no body has any right to but himself. The labour of his body, and the work of his hands, we may say, are properly his. Whatsoever then he removes out of the state that nature hath provided, and left it in, he hath mixed his labour with, and joined to it something that is his own, and thereby makes it his property. It being by him removed from the common state nature hath placed it in, it hath by this labour something annexed to it, that excludes the common right of other men: for this labour being the unquestionable property of the labourer, no man but he can have a right to what that is once joined to, at least where there is enough, and as good, left in common for others.

Sec. 28. He that is nourished by the acorns he picked up under an oak, or the apples he gathered from the trees in the wood, has certainly appropriated them to himself. No body can deny but the nourishment is his. I ask then, when did they begin to be his? when he digested? or when he eat? or when he boiled? or when he brought them home? or when he picked them up? and it is plain, if the first gathering made them not his, nothing else could. That labour put a distinction between them and common: that added something to them more than nature, the common mother of all, had done; and so they became his private right. And will any one say, he had no right to those acorns or apples, he thus appropriated, because he had not the consent of all mankind to make them his? Was it a robbery thus to assume to himself what belonged to all in common? If such a consent as that was necessary, man had starved, notwithstanding the plenty God had given him. We see in commons, which remain so by compact, that it is the taking any part of what is common, and removing it out of the state nature leaves it in, which begins the property; without which the common is of no use. And the taking of this or that part, does not depend on the express consent of all the commoners. Thus the grass my horse has bit; the turfs my servant has cut; and the ore I have digged in any place, where I have a right to them in common with others, become my property, without the assignation or consent of any body. The labour that was mine, removing them out of that common state they were in, hath fixed my property in them.

Sec. 29. By making an explicit consent of every commoner, necessary to any one's appropriating to himself any part of what is given in common, children or servants could not cut the meat, which their father or master had provided for them in common, without assigning to every one his peculiar part. Though the water running in the fountain be every one's, yet who can doubt, but that in the pitcher is his only who drew it out? His labour hath taken it out of the hands of nature, where it was common, and belonged equally to all her children, and hath thereby appropriated it to himself.

...

Sec. 31. It will perhaps be objected to this, that if gathering the acorns, or other fruits of the earth, &c. makes a right to them, then any one may ingross as much as he will. To which I answer, Not so. The same law of nature, that does by this means give us property, does also bound that property too. God has given us all things richly, 1 Tim. vi. 12. is the voice of reason confirmed by inspiration. But how far has he given it us? To enjoy. As much as any one can make use of to any advantage of life before it spoils, so much he may by his labour fix a property in: whatever is beyond this, is more than his share, and belongs to others. Nothing was made by God for man to spoil or destroy. And thus, considering the plenty of natural provisions there was a long time in the world, and the few spenders; and to how small a part of that provision the industry of one man could extend itself, and ingross it to the prejudice of others; especially keeping within the bounds, set by reason, of what might serve for his use; there could be then little room for quarrels or contentions about property so established.

Sec. 32. But the chief matter of property being now not the fruits of the earth, and the beasts that subsist on it, but the earth itself; as that which takes in and carries with it all the rest; I think it is plain, that property in that too is acquired as the former. As much land as a man tills, plants, improves, cultivates, and can use the product of, so much is his property. He by his labour does, as it were, inclose it from the common. Nor will it invalidate his right, to say every body else has an equal title to it; and therefore he cannot appropriate, he cannot inclose, without the consent of all his fellow-commoners, all mankind. God, when he gave the world in common to all mankind, commanded man also to labour, and the penury of his condition required it of him. God and his reason commanded him to subdue the earth, i.e. improve it for the benefit of life, and therein lay out something upon it that was his own, his labour. He that in obedience to this command of God, subdued, tilled and sowed any part of it, thereby annexed to it something that was his property, which another had no title to, nor could without injury take from him.

Sec. 33. Nor was this appropriation of any parcel of land, by improving it, any prejudice to any other man, since there was still enough, and as good left; and more than the yet unprovided could use. So that, in effect, there was never the less left for others because of his enclosure for himself: for he that leaves as much as another can make use of, does as good as take nothing at all. No body could think himself injured by the drinking of another man, though he took a good draught, who had a whole river of the same water left him to quench his thirst: and the case of land and water, where there is enough of both, is perfectly the same.

Sec. 34. God gave the world to men in common; but since he gave it them for their benefit, and the greatest conveniencies of life they were capable to draw from it, it cannot be supposed he meant it should always remain common and uncultivated. He gave it to the use of the industrious and rational, (and labour was to be his title to it;) not to the fancy or covetousness of the quarrelsome and contentious. He that had as good left for his improvement, as was already taken up, needed not complain, ought not to meddle with what was already improved by another's labour: if he did, it is plain he desired the benefit of another's pains, which he had no right to, and not the ground which God had given him in common with others to labour on, and whereof there was as good left, as that already possessed, and more than he knew what to do with, or his industry could reach to.

...

Sec. 36. The measure of property nature has well set by the extent of men's labour and the conveniencies of life: no man's labour could subdue, or appropriate all; nor could his enjoyment consume more than a small part; so that it was impossible for any man, this way, to intrench upon the right of another, or acquire to himself a property, to the prejudice of his neighbour, who would still have room for as good, and as large a possession (after the other had taken out his) as before it was appropriated. This measure did confine every man's possession to a very moderate proportion, and such as he might appropriate to himself, without injury to any body, in the first ages of the world, when men were more in danger to be lost, by wandering from their company, in the then vast wilderness of the earth, than to be straitened for want of room to plant in. And the same measure may be allowed still without prejudice to any body, as full as the world seems: for supposing a man, or family, in the state they were at first peopling of the world by the children of Adam, or Noah; let him plant in some inland, vacant places of America, we shall find that the possessions he could make himself, upon the measures we have given, would not be very large, nor, even to this day, prejudice the rest of mankind, or give them reason to complain, or think themselves injured by this man's incroachment, though the race of men have now spread themselves to all the corners of the world, and do infinitely exceed the small number was at the beginning. Nay, the extent of ground is of so little value, without labour, that I have heard it affirmed, that in Spain itself a man may be permitted to plough, sow and reap, without being disturbed, upon land he has no other title to, but only his making use of it. But, on the contrary, the inhabitants think themselves beholden to him, who, by his industry on neglected, and consequently waste land, has increased the stock of corn, which they wanted. But be this as it will, which I lay no stress on; this I dare boldly affirm, that the same rule of propriety, (viz.) that every man should have as much as he could make use of, would hold still in the world, without straitening any body; since there is land enough in the world to suffice double the inhabitants, had not the invention of money, and the tacit agreement of men to put a value on it, introduced (by consent) larger possessions, and a right to them; which, how it has done, I shall by and by shew more at large.

Sec. 37. This is certain, that in the beginning, before the desire of having more than man needed had altered the intrinsic value of things, which depends only on their usefulness to the life of man; or had agreed, that a little piece of yellow metal, which would keep without wasting or decay, should be worth a great piece of flesh, or a whole heap of corn; though men had a right to appropriate, by their labour, each one of himself, as much of the things of nature, as he could use: yet this could not be much, nor to the prejudice of others, where the same plenty was still left to those who would use the same industry.

...

Sec. 46. The greatest part of things really useful to the life of man, and such as the necessity of subsisting made the first commoners of the world look after, as it cloth the Americans now, are generally things of short duration; such as, if they are not consumed by use, will decay and perish of themselves: gold, silver and diamonds, are things that fancy or agreement hath put the value on, more than real use, and the necessary support of life.

...

Sec. 47. And thus came in the use of money, some lasting thing that men might keep without spoiling, and that by mutual consent men would take in exchange for the truly useful, but perishable supports of life.

...

Sec. 48. And as different degrees of industry were apt to give men possessions in different proportions, so this invention of money gave them the opportunity to continue and enlarge them: for supposing an island, separate from all possible commerce with the rest of the world, wherein there were but an hundred families, but there were sheep, horses and cows, with other useful animals, wholsome fruits, and land enough for corn for a hundred thousand times as many, but nothing in the island, either because of its commonness, or perishableness, fit to supply the place of money; what reason could any one have there to enlarge his possessions beyond the use of his family, and a plentiful supply to its consumption, either in what their own industry produced, or they could barter for like perishable, useful commodities, with others? Where there is not some thing, both lasting and scarce, and so valuable to be hoarded up, there men will not be apt to enlarge their possessions of land, were it never so rich, never so free for them to take: for I ask, what would a man value ten thousand, or an hundred thousand acres of excellent land, ready cultivated, and well stocked too with cattle, in the middle of the inland parts of America, where he had no hopes of commerce with other parts of the world, to draw money to him by the sale of the product? It would not be worth the enclosing, and we should see him give up again to the wild common of nature, whatever was more than would supply the conveniencies of life to be had there for him and his family.

Sec. 49. Thus in the beginning all the world was America, and more so than that is now; for no such thing as money was any where known. Find out something that hath the use and value of money amongst his neighbours, you shall see the same man will begin presently to enlarge his possessions.

Sec. 50. But since gold and silver, being little useful to the life of man in proportion to food, raiment, and carriage, has its value only from the consent of men, whereof labour yet makes, in great part, the measure, it is plain, that men have agreed to a disproportionate and unequal possession of the earth, they having, by a tacit and voluntary consent, found out, a way how a man may fairly possess more land than he himself can use the product of, by receiving in exchange for the overplus gold and silver, which may be hoarded up without injury to any one; these metals not spoiling or decaying in the hands of the possessor. This partage of things in an inequality of private possessions, men have made practicable out of the bounds of society, and without compact, only by putting a value on gold and silver, and tacitly agreeing in the use of money: for in governments, the laws regulate the right of property, and the possession of land is determined by positive constitutions.

Sec. 51. And thus, I think, it is very easy to conceive, without any difficulty, how labour could at first begin a title of property in the common things of nature, and how the spending it upon our uses bounded it. So that there could then be no reason of quarrelling about title, nor any doubt about the largeness of possession it gave. Right and conveniency went together; for as a man had a right to all he could employ his labour upon, so he had no temptation to labour for more than he could make use of. This left no room for controversy about the title, nor for encroachment on the right of others; what portion a man carved to himself, was easily seen; and it was useless, as well as dishonest, to carve himself too much, or take more than he needed.